Sunday, November 18, 2012
Doctors as Salaried Hospital Employees
Our romantic selves continue to cling to the medical ideal
of the friendly GP in solo private practice in an office above the drug
store. The strength of that myth is what
is keeping us from openly recognizing that the prototype health care provider
of the future will be the local hospital that employs its medical staff.
But occasionally, reality creeps through. Page 4A of the November 9 issue of the Omaha
World Herald included a locally written article on changes in medical care as
discussed in a recent forum at the University of Nebraska Medical Center. The following paragraph appeared in the
middle of the article:
“Reimbursement by the government and insurers slowly is
moving away from paying doctors for doing procedures and toward a system in
which doctors are salaried hospital employees and are rewarded for keeping
groups of patients healthy.”
Referring to doctors as salaried hospital employees in a
newspaper article is something few would have dared to do not so long ago. Maybe, at long last, that is changing.
Saturday, November 17, 2012
Saving by Spending
As I think I have mentioned before, I came to realize early
in my career that everything I did to improve efficiency in the hospital cost
more money. Managers and doctors would justify things they wanted to do on the
grounds that they would reduce cost, but when it came time to implement them,
they seemed always to require a budget increase somewhere without an offsetting
decrease somewhere else.
Apparently, things haven’t changed all that much. According to an article in the November 12
issue of the Omaha World Herald, (copied from the Raleigh, NC News and
Observer), “….the federal government is offering as much as $22.5 billion in
incentives for adopting computerized patient records – up to $63,750 per
doctor.”
All of this, of course, is an attempt to make the provision
of health care more efficient by spending more money.
After a few such experiences, I concluded that we in health
care were going about it in the wrong way.
We were trying to improve things without disturbing the underlying
culture and basic structure of the health care establishment and there doesn’t
seem to be any way of doing that. There
are investments that make it possible to reduce cost, but they all involve
changes that affect somebody adversely.
It’s a truth we still haven’t accepted in health care and so
we continue to think we can reduce cost by spending money.
Tuesday, November 13, 2012
A Little Hurrah for Waste, Fraud and Abuse
I read somewhere the other day that part of the 700-odd
billion reduction in Medicare expense used to finance the Accountable Care Act
(a.k.a. Obamacare) was attributed to a projected reduction in waste, fraud and
abuse.
It has occurred to me that perhaps waste, fraud and abuse is
something for which we should be grateful.
It seems that whenever you want to expand an existing social program and
don’t have quite enough income to cover it, you can count on a projected
reduction in waste, fraud and abuse. And
then the next time you want to expand it and are looking around for money,
there is waste, fraud and abuse reduction again waiting to be tapped. One wonders how many social benefits we would
be lacking if it were not for the availability of waste, fraud and abuse
reduction.
So all together now, let’s hear it for waste, fraud and
abuse.
Friday, November 02, 2012
The Fetish of Choice
The idea that free choice of health care provider is some
kind of inalienable right, regardless of who pays the bills, looms as one of
the most important barriers to getting the cost of health care under control.
Although the system of delivering health care has changed a
great deal in recent times, medical practice remains at the center of it. Thus, changing the way medicine is practiced
has to be an essential element of any realistic attempt to restrain or reduce
the cost of health care. Physicians are
not likely to do that on their own. They
practice the way they do because, all things considered, it is the way they
believe works best for them and their patients.
But they would look at it differently if practicing the way
they do came to have adverse economic consequences for them,. If insurance companies were able to refuse to
pay physicians they determine to be wasteful, incompetent, or both, such
physicians would have a powerful incentive to improve.
But the principle of free choice prevents that from
happening. So long as insurance
companies have to pay whatever doctor the beneficiary chooses, a powerful tool
for change will be foregone.
Actually, free choice is not as important as it is made out
to be. When doctors die, retire or move
away, their patients have to find new ones.
People move from one town to another and have to change physicians. When patients go to the emergency room, they
are cared for by whichever physician happens to be on duty at the time. If they get admitted to the hospital as
medical patients, they may well be treated by a hospitalist physician they do
not select. There are few complaints
about any of these things.
But if their insurance company asks them to change doctors
it is considered a violation of a right that politicians of every stripe
promise to protect.
It’s another example of how cost control in health care
requires culture change.