Thursday, August 23, 2012
Canute the Great and Controlling the Cost of Health Care
About a thousand years ago, Canute the Great, a Dane, was
King of England and a big chunk of Scandinavia . Legend has it that one day he set his throne by the sea shore and commanded the
tide to halt and not wet his feet and robes.
I am reminded of
that by the recent enactment of another piece of health reform legislation by
the Commonwealth
of Massachusetts , this
time focused on cost control. Though I
haven’t read the 300-page bill, I conclude from the article about it in the
August 1 issue of the Boston Globe that the approach being taken is not that
much different from that of Canute and the tide. The Massachusetts
government is declaring that health care costs will not rise more rapidly than
the growth of the economy as a whole. It
then admonishes providers to conform to the limit and sets up new government
agencies to watch them as they try.
Much faith seems
to be placed in the conversion of the payment system from fee-for-service to
HMO-style capitation (euphemistically referred to as global payment). The law requires Medicaid and state employee
plans to convert, but only urges private insurance to do so. Commentators doubted that the private sector
would rush to comply.
According to
reports, the tide did not respond to Canute’s command. We’ll see if health care providers in Massachusetts are any
different.
Saturday, August 11, 2012
Creative Destruction
I’m reading Why Nations Fail by Acemoglu and Robinson and
just finished a section on the failure of the Soviet Union . Pages 129 to 132 discuss the various attempts
by the Soviet government to induce people to work harder and more imaginatively
by means of various schemes of rewards and penalties. As a general rule, they failed. Bonuses for increased production led people
to hold production down so as to make increases easier. New and potentially more productive methods
were avoided because they might fail or productivity might diminish during the
transition.
It all caused me to wonder whether we in America might
be doing the same thing in health care.
Government is trying to control cost by implementing schemes like “pay
for performance,” imposing penalties for failing to implement electronic
medical records, and prescribing standards of “meaningful use” as a condition
of grants for implementing information technology. Providers are undoubtedly gaming the system
by devising clever ways to respond to the inducements without making the
changes necessary to achieve cost reduction.
Like the Soviet government, we are afraid of the potential
consequences of competition and of turning people loose to innovate and
experiment. For example, what if it
turned out that with evidence based protocols and an effective system of supervision
by highly trained specialists, bright college graduates with the proper
aptitude and six months of training could do knee replacements with outcomes
better than those now being experienced at two-thirds the cost?
All of that sounds pie-in-the-sky but is it any more radical
than replacing travel agencies with the Internet and personal computers or
replacing local, family-owned stores with Wal-Mart?
What we are talking about here is what Acemoglu and Robinson
call creative destruction, which they argue is essential for enduring economic
progress. Our failure to permit creative
destruction in health care may be important as a reason for high and rising
cost.
Sunday, August 05, 2012
Deductibles and Clinical Responsibility
Health insurance policies with high deductibles are advocated
on the grounds that they cause people to be more prudent in the use of
services. The assumption is that fully
insured patients have a tendency to demand health services they don’t need and
to opt for high cost services when less expensive ones would do just as well. Presumably, having to bear some significant
part of the cost will cause patients to be less likely to make unreasonable
demands.
The issue raises the questions of (a) whether the financial
incentives created by the high deductibles have the intended effect and (b) whether
there are unintended consequences.
Those questions were explored in a column that appeared on
the op-ed page of the July 29 issue of The Boston Globe. The column was stimulated by the personal
experiences of the author, one Joanna Weiss, with a high deductible policy she
and her husband had taken out on their children.
Although there is a dearth of data on the subject, Ms. Weiss
cited anecdotal evidence that at least some people elect high deductible
policies based on a gambling logic; a calculation that they will save more by
electing lower premiums than the high deductibles will cost. Others are responding mainly to the lower premiums
without thinking very much about how they will pay the high deductible if they
ever have to. Some of them later find
they can’t afford the high deductible and go without needed services as a
result.
The other question the issue raises is that of how
responsibility for health care decisions should be allocated between patients
and providers. Under what circumstances
and to what extent should patients make their own decisions about care?
In the past, that question arose in the context of physicians. It was commonly said that a physician who
treated himself (they were mostly men then) had a fool for a doctor and a fool
for a patient. Presumably, the same
would be true of a self-treating patient.
All of the discussion about patient involvement in medical
decisions has the danger, it seems to me, of relieving providers of
responsibility that ought to be theirs.
I think they should be publicly and privately accountable for their
decisions and patients should have a say when the differences are too close to
call, but I think we need a system in which providers have the basic
responsibility for deciding what patients need and which tests and procedures
are the most cost-effective.