Saturday, June 30, 2012
ACA and the Supremes
I have never been a strong fan of the Accountable Care Act
(a.k.a. Obamacare), but given all the circumstances I think it just as well
that it was upheld.
I thought that the cost issue was more important than the
coverage issue and should have been addressed first but others, including wife
Marilyn, failed to find my arguments persuasive. So if we have to get the coverage issue out
of the way before we can address cost, the sooner the better.
As to mandatory health insurance, I was for it when Romney
was for it and Obama was against it. I
continued to be for it after they switched sides. Believing that we would never get single
payer and that everyone would expect care when sick or injured, I have thought
it only fair that everyone be required to contribute.
As to the constitutionality, it was going to be a stretch
however it was decided. The authors of
our constitution could scarcely have anticipated the day when health care would
be considered a social entitlement like food, clothing, and shelter, when it
would represent nearly a fifth of the economy, and when it would be financed
largely by public and private insurance.
There is no way to know how they would have dealt with the question of
whether those electing to remain uninsured should pay a penalty or a tax. So eight of the Supremes voted their politics
and the motives of the ninth remain obscure.
Anyway, the judicial phase of the challenge is now over and
we can go on to the next one.
Saturday, June 23, 2012
Healthcare IT
The Healthcare IT boondoggle continues alive and well.
On a recent visit to one of my medical specialists, I noted
a sign asking me to have my insurance cards ready for reading into a new
computer application.
The doctor and I have a friendly relationship so when he
came into the examining room I mentioned the new application and, as I like to
do in such cases, asked him what problem it was intended to solve.
His immediate answer was “to satisfy the government.” The small specialty group practice to which
he belongs is now being penalized 1% by Medicare for not being computerized and
the penalty rate is expected to go up.
He then, with some apparent emotion, said that the
application cost a lot of money (though Medicare is reimbursing $40,000 of it),
will make his practice less efficient, and affects patient care negatively in
that the new method of communicating with other physicians is less flexible
than the one it replaces.
He mentioned that while one stated intent of computerizing
medical records was to allow the sharing of medical information among
providers, his new application was able to communicate with almost nobody. Even other nearby providers using the same
system could not communicate if it was a different version or if it had been
modified, as many of them had.
We agreed that the effort to automate medical records was
like going from bicycles to space travel without bothering with cars and
airplanes.
And the amount of money being spent is prodigious.
Friday, June 22, 2012
Prospect Theory and Healthcare Reform
For my alumni book group, I’m reading Thinking Fast and Slow
by Nobel Laureate Daniel Kahneman, widely recognized as one of the important
founders of what has come to be known as behavioral economics.
In Kahneman’s Prospect Theory, people weigh losses more
heavily than gains, so that they are to a greater extent affected
psychologically by the loss of a hundred dollars than by a gain of the same
amount.
Prospect Theory has come to take an important place in the
thinking of economists and it occurs to me that it also helps explain why
health care reform is so difficult.
Every reform has winners and losers and, as explained by
Prospect Theory, the losers feel the effects more strongly than the winners.
It is clear to me that the medical profession is the big
loser in health care reform. When my
career in health care began in the 1950’s, doctors were the dominant force in
everything medical. Through the AMA and
state and county medical societies, they controlled medical schools, medical
licensure, state and local health departments, and, for all practical purposes,
hospitals. Until Medicare, it was almost
impossible to enact a piece of legislation that organized medicine opposed.
That level of influence has been diminishing gradually for
some time and health care reform has brought it into steep decline. The role of doctors as arbiters of quality
has been taken over outcomes measurement, clinical protocols and other tools of
the quality movement. The growth of technology,
the increasing complexity of the payment system, and other factors have
strengthened the role of hospitals to the extent that they have largely
supplanted the medical profession as the dominant force in the provider side of
health care.
The profession has largely lost its will to fight back, but
society continues to hold doctors in high esteem and displays no desire to
acknowledge their diminishing role, or even to talk about it. There are various efforts under way to more
effectively integrate the components of medical care and to establish
accountability for outcomes, but none of them come right out and say that this
means that doctors will be part of a system that they no longer control.
It is an unusual application of Prospect Theory, but it
seems to be no less real.
Tuesday, June 19, 2012
No Single Payer in Our Time
“Hope springs eternal” would make a good motto for the
advocates of single payer (a.k.a. national health insurance). A few days ago, I got a large, impressive
looking envelope in the mail from Public Citizen, a Washington D.C.
based advocacy organization. It
contained material inviting me to sign a petition to my U.S. Senators advocating single
payer.
The June 16 issue of The Boston Globe also had a letter or
two urging single payer as the solution to our health care issues.
Single payer may be a good idea and the people who so
persistently urge its adoption are undoubtedly intelligent, sincere, and
well-meaning, but I have news for them.
It isn’t going to happen.
The reason is this: Most
of the politically active people in this country have health insurance and are
satisfied with their coverage. Given
that we already spend too much for health care (if costs are too high, that
means that expenditures are, too.) there is no conceivable program of national
health insurance that would leave these people better off. Some of them would be worse off, and, given
the legendary American distrust of government, the rest are likely to fear that
they might be, too.
No politician skillful enough to earn election to national
office would be likely to vote for anything having such a result. An example has been provided by the
Affordable Care Act (a.k.a. Obamacare).
It contains reform measures much less drastic than single payer and
despite a number of provisions that have been well received, has proved to be
less popular than the President might have hoped for.
For over forty years now I have been predicting that we
would not have national health insurance in the U.S. I’m sticking with it.