Wednesday, March 14, 2012
The Way It Is
Competition is frequently mentioned
as a means of controlling the cost of health care but seldom, if ever, with any
explanation of how it is supposed to do so.
A late example is a story in the
March 13 issue of The Boston Globe reporting an announcement by Kathleen Sebelius,
Secretary of the US Department of Health and Human Services, that guidelines
had been issued for the development of the “new state-based health insurance
markets that will offer consumers one-stop shopping, along the lines of
Amazon.com.” These are the markets
required under the Affordable Care Act, popularly known as ObamaCare.
In her announcement, Secretary
Sibilius said that “More competition will drive down costs….” but made no
mention of how it would do so.
The Secretary presumably was referring to
competition among insurance companies and a reduction in the cost of health
insurance premiums.
Health insurance
premiums cover three main items:
administrative costs, profit and the cost of the services covered by the
insurance policies. Insurance companies
already have an incentive to keep administrative costs as low as they can since
doing so increases profits. Competition no
doubt keeps profits in check, but at their highest they comprise only a few percentage
points of the cost of insurance. Profit
as a percentage of premiums is not rising remarkably and is already restrained
by existing competition among insurance companies.
The big
item making up the cost of premiums is the cost of paying hospitals, doctors
and other providers for the health services used by subscribers. Unless the competition has some impact on
that, its effects on the cost of health care won’t amount to much.
If
competition is to be effective in controlling the cost of health care, it has
to be competition among providers. The
market has to steer patients to providers who provide the best combination of
cost, quality, and patient satisfaction.
The providers who don’t compete successfully in those areas will be
forced out of business.
That may not
sound very pleasant, but that’s the way it is.
Friday, March 09, 2012
Managing Physicians
The current state of the art of managing physicians is
illustrated by the March 6 issue of The Boston Globe, which carried a story
about how the 360 salaried primary care physicians at Partners HealthCare (the
parent company of the Massachusetts General and the Brigham and Women’s
Hospitals) are being offered bonuses of about ten per cent of their salaries
(now roughly $200,000 per year) if they agree to accept more new patients.
It seems that Partners is concerned about the inability of
new patients to get appointments with its physicians and is trying to expand
capacity by offering this inducement.
In most organizations, if management felt that staff members
should be producing more, it would find some direct way to make that known and
expect a response. But apparently that
has not been done at Partners or, if it has, the response has been inadequate
and management has not felt able to do anything about it. Thus the alternative of offering the “carrot”
of more money and hoping it works.
Another implication of the story is that individual primary
care physicians at Partners are making their own decisions about whether to
accept new patients or not. In other
words, each physician is determining his or her workload independently of management. It would be hard to find salaried staff with that
level of freedom anywhere else.
The story mentioned that Leahy Clinic, also located in the Boston area, had adopted
the policy of guaranteeing a new patient an appointment within 48 hours. There was no mention of any financial
inducements associated with that. Leahy
is a long-standing group practice with a great deal of experience in the
employment and management of physicians and apparently has a better handle on
things.
The clear direction of development in the health care delivery
system is the combination of physicians and hospitals into single entities that
can be held accountable for the cost and quality of care. The only way that will work is if all
elements of care, including physicians, are effectively managed. It seems that there is a lot yet to be
learned about how to do that.
Wednesday, March 07, 2012
CHUs and ACOs
A Cultural Hang-Up (CHU for
short) happens when a value or an idea or a practice becomes so firmly engraved
in our cultural subconscious that it keeps us from doing something that is both
sensible and beneficial.
ACOs are a case in point.
ACO is short for Accountable Care Organization, a concept that has been
bandied about in the health care literature for some time and found its way
into the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, known popularly as
ObamaCare. As its name implies, an ACO
is an organization that can be held accountable for both the cost and quality
of care. It is a response to the
historical fragmentation of the health care delivery system, of which the
hospital and its largely independent, self-governing medical staff is perhaps
the most significant example.
The federal government is jumping through all kinds of hoops
trying to define what will qualify as an ACO, apparently based on the premise
that health care will typically be provided under that traditional pattern. How much simpler it would be if the
authorities would just say that the prototype ACO will be a hospital that
employs its medical staff, thereby unifying the major components of care and
acquiring the ability to be held accountable.
There are already institutions like that. Most University-owned teaching hospitals are
medically staffed by employed physicians, as are hospitals operated by large
group practices like Mayo, Cleveland Clinic, Geisinger and Leahy. Such hospitals are very difficult and
expensive to create, however, and there are not likely to be more of them.
Among the private hospitals that quality, The Henry Ford
Hospital in Detroit
is perhaps the best known. The Myrtue Medical
Center in my home town of Harlan , Iowa
is another. Undoubtedly there are
more.
Replicating these examples would be the easiest thing to
do. Hospitals are already hiring
physicians at a rapid rate and the trend could be accelerated by adopting
measures such as grant programs that covered part of the cost, and tax
incentives that encouraged physicians to accept employed status.
But I have yet to hear anyone suggest anything along those
lines. Most likely that is because the
institution of private practice is so deeply entrenched in our culture that any
suggestion that it be replaced is not socially acceptable, even though it is in
steep decline.
CHUs can impede progress.
Thursday, March 01, 2012
The Fetish of Choice
Unrestricted choice of physician is a fetish we have to get
over.
The February 24 issue of the New York Times has a story
about the growing number of PACE programs, under which Medicare pays providers
a lump sum per month to take care of frail seniors. The focus of the story was how PACE programs
keep these seniors in their homes as long as possible – something preferred by
many patients and believed to be less expensive than nursing home care.
It was mentioned in the middle of the story that some
patients “spurn” the program because they refuse to change physicians. Care under PACE is provided by a tightly
organized, pre-selected, carefully managed team that includes doctors, nurses,
social workers, therapists, etc. That
means that in order to participate, a patient has to change doctors, unless his
or her doctor happens already to be member of a PACE team.
As a culture, we cling to the idea that free choice of
physician is something to be highly valued – almost a right. When AARP advertises its Medicare supplement
health insurance policy, it emphasizes that subscribers choose their own
physicians.
At the same time, we are increasingly alarmed about the high
and rising cost of care, not recognizing that the two things are related.
One obvious way to control the cost of care is to manage it
and the PACE program is an attempt to do just that. But in order to manage any activity you have
to organize it and do it systematically.
In the case of health care, that becomes impossible if each patient has
the right independently to pick his or her physician – arguably the most
important person in the care team.
In practice, physician choice is actually not as big a deal
as we make it out to be. People move
from one town to another. Physicians
retire or die. In both cases, patients
have to change doctors. Patients who go
to the emergency room get their care from whatever physician happens to be on
duty at the time. With increasing
frequency, a hospital inpatient is treated by the hospitalist physician who happens
to be assigned to the case. Nobody
complains in these cases. However, if
the insurance company wants us to change physician, we act as though our
persons have been violated.
We need to be weaned off that. One approach we are likely to see is the
health care insurance policy that offers the option of a lower premium if you
use a physician who is a member of the insurance company’s network or panel. Wife Marilyn and I have a primary care
physician we love dearly, but if we could each save $50 a month by changing,
we’d think about it.